التخطي إلى المحتوى الرئيسي

wages in euro-area countries


رشدي ابراهيم، roshdy ebrahim, salaries in europe,monthly salaries in european countries,monthly average salary in european countries,monthly salary in european countries,how many countries in schengen area?,highest paid countries in world,highest paid countries,salary in europe,average salaries in europe,european countries salary?,best salaries in europe,countries,highest salary in european country?,minimum salary in the european union 2020 data all countries,salaries in europe 2021


wages in euro-area countries
Governments in many advanced economies, especially in Europe, currently face the challenge of fiscal consolidation with the need to sustain potential growth. Against this backdrop, the determination of public sector wages has drawn renewed interest in view of its implications for public finances and potential consequences for the efficiency of the public sector and possibly of the whole economy.
Various factors can be adduced to explain public wage-setting behavior and its relationship with private sector wages. While the public sector is subject to political constraints, the private sector is subject to profit constraints. In most cases, the public sector wants to be a good employer and may be willing to pay higher wages to its employees, especially its lower-skilled workers. By contrast, the government might be reluctant to award higher wages to high-skilled workers, as the public opinion might not want to see public servants earning more than comparably trained and experienced private sector counterparts. From an economic perspective, if the government rewards its employees with higher remuneration than in the private sector, prospective workers may decide to queue for these relatively high-paying jobs, with private sector employment crowded out unless private sector wages increase. If, instead, the public sector pays lower wages than in the private sector, it might find it difficult to recruit and retain skilled employees. The result could then be substandard public services.
 Most of the early research on the wage gap between private and public sectors focused on the USA; only a few studies were carried out for non-US countries, and they were mainly based on macro data. At the beginning of the ’90s, a number of papers began to address wage differentials in Europe, Australia and some developing countries.
We use data for the period 2004–2007 for ten European countries: Austria, Belgium, Germany, Spain, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Slovenia. Data are taken from the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC), which collects timely and comparable cross-sectional and longitudinal multidimensional microdata on income, poverty, social exclusion and living conditions. For both the cross-sectional and the longitudinal components, the data are based on nationally representative probability samples of the population residing in private households aged 16 and over, irrespective of language, nationality or legal residence status. To make the sample representative of the whole population, EU-SILC provides sample weights that are used throughout the analysis that follows. We exclude self-employed and, to avoid possible bias arising from self-selection in the labor market participation, we focus on men in the age range 25–65.
We define a public-sector worker as one employed in one of the following sectors according to the NACE (REV 1.1) classification: “Public administration and defense, compulsory social security”, “Education”, and “Health and social work”.
Such an approximation tends to overestimate the share of public sector workers in total employees, as some of the employees included in NACE sectors “Education” and “Health and social work” are involved in activities classified as market/private services (e.g. private hospitals and private schools). The share of such activities varies across countries. For Germany, where health services are mainly provided by the private sector, health sector workers are excluded from our definition of public sector. In our sample, the share of public sector employees range between 19% Germany and 38% Belgium. As for the private sector, manufacturing and retail account for the largest shares in all countries, representing altogether about half of the total. Other peculiarities are country specific.
On average, the overall wage gap is positive for all the countries. However, its size varies considerably across countries: it ranges between 6 and 16%in Austria, Belgium, Germany and France; it is around 30%in Italy, Ireland and Slovenia and 35% in Greece and Spain; it is above 40% in Portugal. Workers’ characteristics explain more than two-thirds of the overall gap in Austria, France, Slovenia and Germany, slightly more than one half in Portugal, but only between 45 and 32%in Ireland, Greece, Italy and Spain. Differences in wages that are explained by different levels of endowments can be justified as a return on investment. The unexplained component of the overall pay gap can instead be viewed as a premium or a penalty. The price effect is greater than the endowment effect in Spain, Greece, Ireland and Italy. Belgium is the only country where the unexplained component of the wage differential is negative, implying a penalty for working in the public sector. In Austria, France, Germany and Slovenia, we estimate a premium of about 6% or less. In the other countries, the premium is higher: in Italy, Ireland, Greece and Portugal, it ranges from 17 to 20%, whereas in Spain it reaches 24%.
What are the determinants of the premium is hard to tell, as there is no clear-cut evidence about the importance of each explanatory variable. Investment in education is rewarded significantly more in the public sector only in Austria, Spain and Ireland.
In Belgium, Italy and Portugal, the price effect associated with education is actually slightly negative and significant. As for experience, in most countries, its contribution is either not statistically significant or negative. Indeed, the largest part of the public-sector premium comes from the intercept. If we run region-specific regressions, the differences in the intercept decrease significantly, suggesting that local labor market conditions might explain differences in pay between the two sectors.
In Austria, the overall wage gap is (almost) flat as both components remain constant along the wage distribution. For a large part of the wage distribution, the overall wage gap remains flat in most of the other countries (Belgium, France, Slovenia, Spain and Greece); it is decreasing in Germany, and somewhat increasing in Ireland, Italy and Portugal. As also found by other studies, the wage gap in favor of public sector employees can be attributed to larger premia (price effect) at the bottom tail of the wage distributions (where public sector workers do not appear to be better endowed than private sector employees) and better endowments at high wage levels, which compensate for smaller premia or even penalties from working in the public sector.
Furthermore, with respect to the existing literature, we also account for the rate of change of the pay gap along the distribution. As a measure of the symmetry of the gap, we calculate the interquartile range of the decomposition, i.e. the differences in the coefficients at the 90th and the 50th quantiles and at the 50th and the 10th quantiles.
Comparing these two differences, a larger negative number in the 90–50th quantile difference on the unexplained part than in 50–10th difference implies that the fall in the premium when moving from lower to higher wage levels is larger at the right end of the distribution than at the left end. In all countries, except Germany and Italy, the premium decreases faster from the median onward than below the median. By contrast, the contribution of the explained factors increases faster at the right side of the distribution than at the left.
We further decompose the endowment effect and the price effect into the contribution of each explanatory variable. Differences in education represent the largest portion of the endowment effect at all quantiles and for all countries, reflecting the larger shares of secondary and tertiary educated workers in the public sector than in the private sector. The impact of differences in education is much larger at the top than at the bottom of the wage distribution.
As for the price effect, the premium from education is positive up to the median or so in Austria, Spain, Greece, Ireland, Italy and Slovenia, negligible in Belgium and France, and negative in Portugal. At the upper end of the wage distribution, the contribution of education in explaining the public–private wage premium is much lower or even negative in almost all the countries. This outcome suggests that the higher return on educational investment in the public sector tends to vanish when we move from low to high wages.
(Abstract from Public–private wage differentials in euro-area countries: evidence from quantile decomposition analysis article).



تعليقات

المشاركات الشائعة من هذه المدونة

الفكر الاقتصادي في العصور الوسطى الأوروبية

العصور الوسطى الأوروبية: في القرون من التاسع حتى الخامس عشر الميلادية ساد في أوربا التكوين الاجتماعي الاقطاعي، وتتميز طريقة انتاجه التي بدأت في فرنسا ثم انتشرت في انجلترا وباقي مجتمعات أوروبا: ــ بأن العلاقات الاجتماعية للانتاج تدور أساسا حول الأرض التي تصبح البلورة المادية للملكية العقارية، اذ هي ترتكز على اقتصاد يغلب عليه الطابع الزراعي. ــ لمن يقومون بالعمل في الانمتاج الزراعي حق استعمال الأرض وشغلها. أما حق ملكيته فهو على درجات لهرم من السادة تحدده التقاليد والعادات. ــ هذا الأساس الاقتصادي يقابله شبكة من الروابط الشخصية، جزء من العاملين لا يتمتع بكامل حريته الشخصية حيث أنهم أقنان، أما السادة فيرتبط نظام ملكيتهم بنظام من الواجبات يتحمل بها كل منهم في مواجهة من هو أعلى منه. وتجد طريقة الانتاج هذه جذورها في المجتمع القديم حين بدأ كبار ملاك الأراضي يقاومون سلطة روما عن طريق الاقامة في ملكياتهم العقارية وتوسيع هذه الملكيات بالسيطرة على الملكيات الأصغر والمزارع المهجورة. في هذا النظام توجد جذور نظام الأقنان، غير أن هذا لا يعني أن القن وجد كنتيجة للتحرر الجزئي للعبد وانما ي...

مفهوم التخلف والدولة المتخلفة

لقد تعددت مسميات الدول الفقيرة فهناك من يطلق عليها الدول المتأخرة لأنها لم تصل الى مستوى مرتفع من التقدم الفني والاقتصادي , كما أطلق عليها الدول المتخلفة حيث تنخفض فيها مستويات المعيشة عن تلك المستويات السائدة في دول أوروبا , كما أطلق عيها الدول النامية حيث تقوم هذه الدول بمجهود انمائي , كما أطلق عليها أخيرا دول العالم الثالث حيث أن هذه الدول لا تمثل مجموعة متجانسة يمكن أن يشملها تعريف واحد. والحقيقة أنه لا يوجد أي فرق جوهري في هذه المسميات ولكننا سنتفق علي مصطلح الدول المتخلفة. أولا: مفهوم التخلف:- هناك ثلاث اتجاهات رئيسية لتعريف وتحديد التخلف نتناولهم كالآتي:- 1-                       الاتجاه الأول: يقوم هذا الاتجاه بحصر سمات ومظاهر التخلف المتمثلة في انخفاض متوسط الأجور ومستويات المعيشة والاستثمار وانتشار البطالة. ويركز هذا الاتجاه على انخفاض الدخل القومي مما يؤدي الى انخفاض متوسط دخل الفرد وذلك يؤدي الى انخفاض معدل الاشتثمار مما يؤدي الى انخفاض الدخل وبالتالي ترسيخ جذور ا...

نظرية الانتاج

نظرية الانتاج ـ الانتاج يتمثل في الجهد الانساني الذي يبذل لجعل الموارد الاقتصادية صالحة لاشباع الحاجات الانسانية، وهو جهد يتضمن علاقة مزدوجة. علاقة بين الانسان والطبيعة، وعلاقة بين الانسان والانسان. ـ تتطلب عملية الانتاج توافر العناصر الآتية: القوة العاملة وأدوات العمل وموضوع العمل. ـ تضم نظرية الانتاج موضوعات عديدة أهمها: عناصر الانتاج وكيفية التأليف بين هذه العناصر وأشكال المشروعات القائمة الانتاج، واتجاهات هذه المشروعات. ـ عناصر الانتاج وتسمى أيضا عناصر المشروع هي الموارد التي يستخدمها المجتمع في انتاج ما يحتاجه من سلع وخدمات، عناصر الانتاج أربعة: الطبيعة والعمل ورأس المال والتنظيم. ـ الموارد الطبيعية كعنصر من عناصر الانتاج هي كافة هبات الطبيعة التي لم يوجدها عمل انساني سابق ولا حاضر والتي تمكن الانسان من انتاج السلع والخدمات التي يحتاجها لاشباع حاجاته. ـ الطبيعة عنصر سلبي في الانتاج. ـ هناك عدة عوامل اساسية تحكم مدى كفاية الموارد الطبيعية لحاجة الانسان اليها للقيام بنشاطه الانتاجي وهي على سبيل الحصر: 1-          ...