التخطي إلى المحتوى الرئيسي

Regulation effects on the adoption of new medicines

رشدي ابراهيم، roshdy ebrahim, adoption,medicine,medicine (field of study),celebrities who gave up their kids for adoption,celebrities who gave their kids up for adoption,emory department of medicine,the new york times,celebs who gave up their kids for adoption,celebs who gave their kids up for adoption,paul sunderland adoption and addiction,emory university school of medicine,adoption issues later in life,national association of social workers,adoption issues,regulation,adoption process


Regulation effects on the adoption of new medicines
Pharmaceutical products typically face a number of regulatory hurdles; evidence on the quality, safety and efficacy of new molecules is estimated to take around ten years of pre-clinical and clinical research time. Following review of the new product dossier by a regulatory authority such as the Food and Drug Authority (FDA) in the USA or the European Medicines Agency (EMA) in the EC, marketing authorization is established, which defines the relevant patient population and therapeutic use.
Lags in the adoption of innovative pharmaceutical products are then the result of different influences in different countries, but of great importance are local price and reimbursement regulations. Several studies in the literature have addressed delays attributable to drug review processes generally, while more recent studies have emphasized price controls and variations in reimbursement schemes.
The first way, as used by, uses treatment dummies to identify whether price controls exist at the time of launch. Similarly, Heuer et al. use dichotomous variable approach to identify both direct price regulations (international price comparisons, therapeutic value/cost-effectiveness and pharmaceutical contribution to the economy) and indirect price regulations (profit control and reference pricing). The latter is used in a discrete choice analysis to test how different pricing and reimbursement schemes affect the probability of launch for NCEs approved by the centralized EMA procedure within the former EU15 during 1995–2004. estimates a discrete-time survival model using data in 28 countries over 1980–2000 using a ranking of price bands and regulation dummies to indicate whether prescription budgets, reference pricing, price freezes and controls affect launch times. Studies using this first definition identify a significant effect of price controls on the probability of launch. Countries with the highest probability of launch impose the lowest regulation on prices and indirect price controls do not affect launch delays significantly for on-patent drugs further observes that launch in a price-controlled country significantly reduces the likelihood of introducing products in additional markets.
Treatment dummies and price ranking control for regulation only approximately and are potentially inaccurate given the dynamic and multidimensional nature of regulation.
Price ranking, for example, may be highly heterogeneous with respect to therapeutic subgroups or across time. In addition, treatment dummies frequently exhibit multicollinearity with country effects. Partly in reaction to these criticisms, there is a more recent, preliminary body of literature, which has incorporated product-specific data on actual prices to identify the impact of regulation empirically.
These studies differ broadly in how they define product prices and tend to emphasize the formulation of firm’s expectations over how price and reimbursement controls will affect price on entry. proxy expected price by the lagged average price per standard unit (SU) for the therapeutic class (ATC3) in quarters 3 and 4 prior to the first global launch, in an attempt to capture a firm’s expectation over the impact of price controls. While use the average competitor prices in the therapeutic class (at the finer ATC4 level) prior to local launch as a measure of this expectation. In terms of specification, use the continuous time Cox proportional hazard (PH) model, whereas the latter study uses discrete-time implementation of the PH model by complementary log–log regression. Findings from the second category of studies, which use explicit definitions of expected product price, suggest that the hazard of launch is positively related to expected price, once again implying that price controls have a negative impact on launch timings.
In addition to regulatory market barriers, late entry may reflect strategic firm behavior to avoid the effects of price spillovers due to reference pricing and parallel trade.
proxy such spillover effects through overall market size, identifying a significant market size effect, whereas conclude that total volume of drugs in a therapeutic subgroup is not a significant factor affecting launch time.
Intercontinental Medical Statistics (IMS) data are used with quarterly sales data, in US$, over the period 1999 (Q1)–2008 (Q3). The data used relate to standard unit (SU) sales of new molecules in 13 different ATC1 therapeutic categories during 1999 Q1–2008 Q3. The dataset comprises 20 countries, which represent the major pharmaceutical markets in the OECD (plus South Africa). Each product is identified by the molecule name, IMS generic classification, global and local launch dates, therapeutic class (ATC4) and breakdown of sales by the distribution channel (retail versus hospital).
Spain, Turkey, Belgium, Greece, Portugal, Spain and South Africa have only retail channel data; in Sweden, retail and hospital sales are combined.
The global launch date of a given molecule defines the onset of risk of subsequent launches in other markets. The launch dates are recorded monthly. The unit of analysis is molecule–country pairs. The time to launch for each molecule j–country k pair is defined as the difference between the global launch date of molecule j and the local launch date of molecule j in country k. The dataset is expanded to define monthly time intervals following the global launch date until the local failure (launch or censoring) to account for the interval-censored nature of the launch timing data. Our empirical strategy takes advantage of the variation in launch dates, which is attributable to the various expectations held by producers over the price and sales volume attainable in individual markets, the regulatory environment and the degree of market competition.
The molecule set is restricted to molecules that have launched in at least ten markets, which is a more stringent measure of global importance compared to prior studies.
Prior studies at best consider either molecules that have launched in the USA or UK, and our analysis is more complete in this respect. Our sample contains molecules that launched after 1999, and the total number of molecules in this set is 22,397, with a median time to launch of 14 months.
The analysis uses ex-manufacturer price levels ignoring any marketing discounts and mark-ups across wholesalers and retailers, and we focus on the regulated price.
The price for all molecules is calculated by dividing the ex-manufacturer total revenue by volume in SU sales. For all remaining markets, IMS data include retail prescription, pharmacy and hospital data. Obviously, given the range of discounts and co-payments that apply across these different sectors, our calculated price will only ever proxy the true selling prices, but the ex-manufacturing price is the price at which national prices are negotiated. Moreover, estimated country fixed effects should account for some of the variation in country-specific discounts. Quarterly average price is assumed for each month in a given quarter, and the price calculated essentially estimates a volume weighted average price for each molecule across all products with the same active ingredient.
Further (confounding) variables are defined using the IMS data on sales, including an Herfindahl-Hirschman Index of global market competition, firm size as proxied by sales volume and product quality as established by molecule characteristics.
OECD statistical extracts were obtained for additional data on GDP per capita. Sales data were deflated using GDP deflators from the International Monetary Fund World Economic Outlook Database 2008.
Our main result for the impact of price regulation on the timing of the launch of a new molecule is significant and strongly robust across these specifications. In all regression specifications the estimates for our measure of the impact of price regulation, the expected price, after controlling for volume are highly significant (p=0.001).
A unit increase in the log expected launch price and the log of expected market size increases the probability of launch by 0.003 and 0.002, respectively. This is close in value to 0.0053, the marginal effect of expected price for superior molecules. Standard error estimates of expected price are slightly lower because we cluster by molecule–country rather than by molecule alone.
The latter is expected given the presence of price (regulation) benchmarking across countries with are specific for each molecule.
With respect to other effects, for competition, a unit increase in the log of IHH reduces the hazard rate by 0.005 in the quadratic specification and by 0.004 in the semi-parametric one, which implies the more competitive the subgroup, the higher is the likelihood of quick launch. In other words, and in common with many other industries, the higher the concentration, the lower is the likelihood of rapid launch. Firm heterogeneity, proxied by the number of countries a firm has launched in, is found to be highly significant; a unit increase in the log number of countries a firm has launched in (equivalent to multiplying geographical reach by 2.72) reduces the probability of delay by 0.01. With respect to molecule characteristics, a unit increase in the log molecule sales globally increases the hazard of launch by 0.004. The extent of global reach, as expected, was found to have a significantly positive effect on the probability of launch with a marginal effect of 0.059. The only caveat of our approach is that it might introduce a bias for older molecules as they have had more observed time to launch in more markets, although we do control for time since first global launch. The effect of country income, as given by log GDP per capita ($), is positive but not significant, and is therefore excluded from some specifications.
Finally, time may affect regression estimates in several ways. First, macroeconomic trends in the sector may have an impact on price levels, so we account for this by including dummies for each calendar year in all regressions. Second, time captures information about the relative innovativeness of new molecules. When a new molecule is about to launch, it represents incremental (or breakthrough) innovation compared to the molecules in its therapeutic subclass. The longer the time lapse from global launch, the higher is the probability that new competitors will enter to compete against the molecule lowering its comparative therapeutic advantage. The impact of time elapsed since first global launch is therefore captured by interacting expected price, as well as volume with the time since global launch. A dummy variable (first launch before 1999) is also included to test whether the hazard of launch is statistically different for molecules that launched globally after 1999 compared to the ones that launched first globally during (1993 and 1999). Remember that the set of molecules was restricted to the ones that first launched after the establishment of the EU in 1993 and that all the failures (i.e. local launches) are post-1999. Therefore, molecules with first global launch pre-1999 are left-truncated. Left-truncation is dealt with by omitting the subject from all binary outcome analyses during the truncation period since the subject could not have failed during that period.
Time interactions of price and volume are significantly negative, which suggests that the impact of price and volume decays over time following the global launch of the molecule. Molecules that launched first before 1999 have a significantly lower hazard rate compared to molecules that launched after 1999; the marginal effect is in the range of 0.018 to 0.014 depending on the precise model specification.
Parameter estimates of t and t2 suggest concave duration dependence, while the hazard of launch initially increases and then decreases, which is in contrast to prior findings of Danzon and Epstein (2008) who observed that hazards first decrease then increase with time since global launch. This might be because the molecules in this analysis are more recent, and hence potentially more innovative and have a higher extent of global reach overall (all molecules have launched in at least 10 markets).
Given that we use proxies for a number of our confounding variables, we carry out a number of robustness checks. With respect to competition effects, we carry out robustness checks by controlling for the number of substitute molecules and investigate whether generic competition is significant. We consider only quadratic duration specification for robustness checks as base case estimates suggest the fit of quadratic and semi-parametric specifications are comparable. Intermolecular competition is found to be more influential on the decision of entry, as compared to the extent of generic competition proxied by the number of substitute molecules with generic competition. This is consistent with findings of Kyle (2007) that the number of competitor molecules in the same ATC4 significantly increases the hazard of launch, while the number of molecules with generic competition has no significant effect on the launch decision of new molecules.
Robustness checks were carried out by controlling for log firm sales in 2007; total and local numbers of firm molecules firms have launched to control for economies of scope. All scale and scope variables are robustly positive and significant. Portfolio diversity (number of prior molecules launched) is associated with quicker launch, which is in contrast to findings of Kyle (2007). We find no evidence of advantage through domestic launch.
In the robustness checks on molecule characteristics, we further proxied therapeutic importance using the total number of markets in which a molecule has launched, i.e. global extent of launch.
Finally, we also aimed to explicitly test for the potential impact of price interdependency across country markets. We therefore restricted the country set to EU countries. We find strong evidence that external reference pricing slows adoption of innovation. Launch in a high-priced EU market increases the conditional probability of launch by 0.042 compared to launch in a lower-priced EU market. This effect increases to 0.051 for molecules that first launched after 1999, suggesting an increase in the strategic importance of price in the timing of entry.
From a strategic perspective, firms may risk the loss of competitive innovative edge as delays increase the chance of facing further competition later in time.
This suggests a second firm strategy, which involves pursuing convergence of prices in the EU market following launch to avoid knock-on effects due to parallel trade and external referencing, even if at the expense of foregoing some short-term local profits in some markets. We test for this strategy, by controlling for the extent of deviation between expected local price and the average EU price for the launching molecule. The absolute difference between the local expected price and average EU price significantly decreases the hazard of launch; the sign of this difference remains insignificant. Launch and pricing strategies are multimarket optimization decisions; the trend to drive prices closer across different geographies may potentially reduce global prices.
Thus, to summarize, regardless of the precise time duration specification, and controlling for a large number of confounding effects, price regulatory controls on reimbursement have a strong effect on time to launch. Across a range of specifications and definitions, we also find weak competition increases time-to-entry, while larger market size, higher therapeutic importance and the greater the number of markets a firm operates in reduces time-to-entry. We further find that within the confines of the EC market where, although individual countries have their own price and reimbursement authorities, there is considerable cross-referencing of pharmaceutical prices and parallel importing of pharmaceutical products, price regulatory spillover effects appear to have an impact on launch times.
(Abstract from Joan Costa-Font · Alistair McGuire · Nebibe Varol article)

تعليقات

المشاركات الشائعة من هذه المدونة

الفكر الاقتصادي في العصور الوسطى الأوروبية

العصور الوسطى الأوروبية: في القرون من التاسع حتى الخامس عشر الميلادية ساد في أوربا التكوين الاجتماعي الاقطاعي، وتتميز طريقة انتاجه التي بدأت في فرنسا ثم انتشرت في انجلترا وباقي مجتمعات أوروبا: ــ بأن العلاقات الاجتماعية للانتاج تدور أساسا حول الأرض التي تصبح البلورة المادية للملكية العقارية، اذ هي ترتكز على اقتصاد يغلب عليه الطابع الزراعي. ــ لمن يقومون بالعمل في الانمتاج الزراعي حق استعمال الأرض وشغلها. أما حق ملكيته فهو على درجات لهرم من السادة تحدده التقاليد والعادات. ــ هذا الأساس الاقتصادي يقابله شبكة من الروابط الشخصية، جزء من العاملين لا يتمتع بكامل حريته الشخصية حيث أنهم أقنان، أما السادة فيرتبط نظام ملكيتهم بنظام من الواجبات يتحمل بها كل منهم في مواجهة من هو أعلى منه. وتجد طريقة الانتاج هذه جذورها في المجتمع القديم حين بدأ كبار ملاك الأراضي يقاومون سلطة روما عن طريق الاقامة في ملكياتهم العقارية وتوسيع هذه الملكيات بالسيطرة على الملكيات الأصغر والمزارع المهجورة. في هذا النظام توجد جذور نظام الأقنان، غير أن هذا لا يعني أن القن وجد كنتيجة للتحرر الجزئي للعبد وانما ي...

مفهوم التخلف والدولة المتخلفة

لقد تعددت مسميات الدول الفقيرة فهناك من يطلق عليها الدول المتأخرة لأنها لم تصل الى مستوى مرتفع من التقدم الفني والاقتصادي , كما أطلق عليها الدول المتخلفة حيث تنخفض فيها مستويات المعيشة عن تلك المستويات السائدة في دول أوروبا , كما أطلق عيها الدول النامية حيث تقوم هذه الدول بمجهود انمائي , كما أطلق عليها أخيرا دول العالم الثالث حيث أن هذه الدول لا تمثل مجموعة متجانسة يمكن أن يشملها تعريف واحد. والحقيقة أنه لا يوجد أي فرق جوهري في هذه المسميات ولكننا سنتفق علي مصطلح الدول المتخلفة. أولا: مفهوم التخلف:- هناك ثلاث اتجاهات رئيسية لتعريف وتحديد التخلف نتناولهم كالآتي:- 1-                       الاتجاه الأول: يقوم هذا الاتجاه بحصر سمات ومظاهر التخلف المتمثلة في انخفاض متوسط الأجور ومستويات المعيشة والاستثمار وانتشار البطالة. ويركز هذا الاتجاه على انخفاض الدخل القومي مما يؤدي الى انخفاض متوسط دخل الفرد وذلك يؤدي الى انخفاض معدل الاشتثمار مما يؤدي الى انخفاض الدخل وبالتالي ترسيخ جذور ا...

نظرية الانتاج

نظرية الانتاج ـ الانتاج يتمثل في الجهد الانساني الذي يبذل لجعل الموارد الاقتصادية صالحة لاشباع الحاجات الانسانية، وهو جهد يتضمن علاقة مزدوجة. علاقة بين الانسان والطبيعة، وعلاقة بين الانسان والانسان. ـ تتطلب عملية الانتاج توافر العناصر الآتية: القوة العاملة وأدوات العمل وموضوع العمل. ـ تضم نظرية الانتاج موضوعات عديدة أهمها: عناصر الانتاج وكيفية التأليف بين هذه العناصر وأشكال المشروعات القائمة الانتاج، واتجاهات هذه المشروعات. ـ عناصر الانتاج وتسمى أيضا عناصر المشروع هي الموارد التي يستخدمها المجتمع في انتاج ما يحتاجه من سلع وخدمات، عناصر الانتاج أربعة: الطبيعة والعمل ورأس المال والتنظيم. ـ الموارد الطبيعية كعنصر من عناصر الانتاج هي كافة هبات الطبيعة التي لم يوجدها عمل انساني سابق ولا حاضر والتي تمكن الانسان من انتاج السلع والخدمات التي يحتاجها لاشباع حاجاته. ـ الطبيعة عنصر سلبي في الانتاج. ـ هناك عدة عوامل اساسية تحكم مدى كفاية الموارد الطبيعية لحاجة الانسان اليها للقيام بنشاطه الانتاجي وهي على سبيل الحصر: 1-          ...